Paul Krugman. November 5, 1996. Extract from his debate
with Galbraith on Slate on "Who
is the Real Economist?"
"Economics is at
least partly about quantities and their relationships; so you can't make
sense of it unless you are willing to do some arithmetic and even some
algebra to make sure that the stories you tell hang together--and that
they are consistent with the evidence. This doesn't sound like much, but
experience shows that there are many influential intellectuals who are
prepared to make sweeping pronouncements on economics without doing the
arithmetic. And by the way, throwing around lots of statistics is not the
point: It's a question of thinking hard about how the statistics fit together.
Maybe the only way to explain what
I am talking about is to give an example. It involves Michael Lind of The
New Yorker, against whom I have no particular grudge--in fact, part
of the point is that he is, undoubtedly, a very smart guy. That is what
makes this particular example so revealing: It shows what happens when
someone who is very bright but does not understand the role of arithmetic
in economic analysis tries to make pronouncements on the subject.
Two years ago, Lind wrote the following
in Harper's:
Many advocates of free trade claim that higher productivity growth in the United States will offset any downward pressure on wages caused by the global sweatshop economy, but the appealing theory falls victim to an unpleasant fact. Productivity has been going up, without resulting wage gains for American workers. Between 1977 and 1992, the average productivity of American workers increased by more than 30 percent, while the average real wage fell by 13 percent. The logic is inescapable. No matter how much productivity increases, wages will fall if there is an abundance of workers competing for a scarcity of jobs--an abundance of the sort created by the globalization of the labor pool for U.S.-based corporations.
Now what should Lind
have done before publishing this passage? He should have had an internal
monologue--something like this: "Hmm, do these numbers make sense?
Well, historically, compensation of workers has been around 70 percent
of national income. So let's say that initially, output per worker is 100,
and the wage is 70. Now if productivity is up 30 percent, that means that
output is 130, while if wages are down 13 percent, that brings the wage
down to around 61, which is less than half of 130--wow, that means that
the share of labor in national income must have fallen more than 20 percentage
points. Let me check that out in the Statistical Abstract. ..."
Of course, if he had, he would have found out that the share of compensation
in national income, far from declining 20 percentage points, was about
the same (73 percent) in 1992 as it was in 1977, offering a clear warning
bell that something was wrong not only with his numbers--for example, he
turns out to have confused productivity in manufacturing with productivity
in the economy as a whole--but with his story. (This was not a throwaway
passage marginal to his main argument; the claim that globalization has
shifted the distribution of income drastically in favor of capital was
central to his article.)
How could Lind have failed to go through
this little monologue? Well, I have had several conversations with impressive,
highly articulate men, who believe themselves sophisticated about economic
matters, but who simply do not understand that if productivity is up and
wages are down, this must mean that labor's share in income has fallen.
These conversations are not pleasant: They want to discuss deep global
issues, and end up being given a lesson in elementary arithmetic. But that
is precisely the point: All too many people think that they can do economics
by learning some impressive phrases and reciting some gee-whiz statistics,
and do not realize that you need to think algebraically about how the story
fits together."