January 24, 2002
The Civilizing Effect
Of Market Economics
THE MARKETPLACE allocates resources efficiently and
unsentimentally, pausing to contemplate neither fairness nor feelings. So one
might expect people in societies that embrace money and the market to be
richer, but less generous and altruistic, than small bands who hunt and farm
communally in isolated parts of the Amazon or Africa.
But is that reality? American generosity after Sept. 11
doesn't suggest hard-heartedness. What if we randomly picked pairs of people
from the same community and did an experiment? Tell neither the other's
identity. Offer Player One $100, and test his generosity by telling him to
split the money any way he chooses with Player Two, who knows how big the
stakes are. Add one catch to restrain Player One from being selfish: If Player
Two refuses the offer, neither gets anything.
A coldly rational person -- think bond traders -- would
offer as little as possible, maybe $10. And if Player Two were coldly rational,
he would accept; after all, $10 is better than no dollars. But such people
exist only in economists' minds.
In repeated experiments of this sort, people cast as
Player One were more generous than the calculating bond trader. And people cast
as Player Two were more likely to reject small offers, even though that left
them with nothing. This left economists scratching their heads and wondering
why we don't act as their theories say we should.
Along the way, they wondered what sorts of people act
more generously: Nomadic Hazda hunter-gatherers who forage in Tanzania? Or
farmers in Hamilton, Mo., in the heart of our market-oriented society?
Americans, it turns out. Hazda cast as Player One offered
the equivalent of $33 on average. Hamiltonians in the same role offered $48.
Anthropologists didn't use the same sums in both places, of course. The stakes
were roughly a day's pay in each.
THE PATTERN across societies where experiments were
conducted is counterintuitive, but consistent. The more involved people are in
market activities -- such as working for wages or buying and selling goods to
others -- the more generous they are. "The most altruistic and trusting
societies are those that are the most market-oriented," says Jean
Ensminger, an anthropologist at the California Institute of Technology,
Pasadena.
Experiments aren't precise substitutes for real life. But
by doing enough experiments, using substantial stakes and sifting results
statistically, researchers are uncovering ways in which people tend to behave
differently depending on where they grow up.
See more information about some of the items mentioned in
this column.
* * *
At first, the researchers experimented with college
students in Indonesia, Japan, Slovenia and the U.S. They found few differences.
That simply proved that college students tend to be alike no matter where
they're from.
Then a young anthropologist named Joseph Henrich, who was
doing unrelated fieldwork in the Peruvian Amazon, found that these games could
be played with unsophisticated people. His work offered early evidence that
people in primitive societies might be less generous with one another than we
are.
Intrigued foundations dispatched a dozen anthropologists
to play this and other games with 15 communities from the Orma in East Africa,
who often trade cattle and work for wages, to the Quichua in Ecuador, who
don't. The games also were played in rural Hamilton and urban St. Louis.
EXPERIMENTS DON'T REVEAL why market-oriented people like
the Orma make more-generous offers ($44 on average) than subsistence,
slash-and-burn farmers like the Quichua ($25). Nor do they explain why
Americans and others in market-oriented settings come much closer to offering
partners a 50-50 split than other people do. But the games do suggest something
profound about the way markets shape human behavior and relationships.
"Many people thought markets would make people
selfish and amoral. That view is at least too simple, if not just plain
wrong," says Samuel Bowles, an economist at the University of
Massachusetts and the Santa Fe Institute.
Maybe, suggests Ms. Ensminger, altruism is a luxury that
only developed societies can afford. Or maybe market societies grow accustomed
to conventions, like splitting windfalls 50-50. Or maybe, as she and other
researchers suspect, markets do change the way people behave, but not in the
way we often think.
"Markets teach us to behave decently to
strangers," Mr. Bowles speculates. "Markets are an arena in which you
encounter somebody you've never seen before and engage in mutually beneficial
activity." In a society without markets, people deal mainly with familiar faces.
They have little practice in one-time transactions with anonymous strangers.
People overlook "assumptions about trust that are
built into the market economy," adds Mr. Henrich, who will join Emory
University's faculty this year. "When you take a taxi, you could walk out
without paying the fare," he says. "But people generally don't."
The same goes for tipping in restaurants.
Sure, some Americans stiff cab drivers and waiters. But
not very many. And that offers a heartening counterpoint at a moment when Enron
exposes the excesses and greed of a market society.
-- David Wessel
Write to David Wessel at capital@wsj.com
------------------------------------------------------------------------
Return to top of page
Copyright © 2002 Dow Jones & Company, Inc. All Rights
Reserved.
Copyright and reprint information.