There
is a school of thought that argues that what a firm pays in dividends is
irrelevant and that stockholders are indifferent about receiving dividends.
Like the capital structure irrelevance proposition, the dividend irrelevance
argument has its roots in a paper crafted by Miller and Modigliani.
The
underlying intuition for the dividend irrelevance proposition is simple. Firms
that pay more dividends offer less price appreciation but must provide the same
total return to stockholders, given their risk characteristics and the cash
flows from their investment decisions. Thus, there are no taxes, or if
dividends and capital gains are taxed at the same rate, investors should be
indifferent to receiving their returns in dividends or price appreciation.
For
this argument to work, in addition to assuming that there is no tax advantage
or disadvantage associated with dividends, we also have to assume the
following:
á
There are no transactions costs associated with
converting price appreciation into cash, by selling stock. If this were not
true, investors who need cash urgently might prefer to receive dividends.
á
Firms that pay too much in dividends can issue stock,
again with no flotation or transactions costs, to take on good projects. There
is also an implicit assumption that this stock is fairly priced.
á
The investment decisions of the firm are unaffected by
its dividend decisions, and the firmÕs operating cash flows are the same no
matter which dividend policy is adopted.
á
Managers of firms that pay too little in dividends do
not waste the cash pursuing their own interests (i.e., managers with large free
cash flows do not use them to take on bad projects).
Under these assumptions, neither the firms paying the
dividends nor the stockholders receiving them will be adversely affected by
firms paying either too little or too much in dividends.
To
provide a formal proof of irrelevance, assume that an LongLast Corporation, an unlevered
firm manufacturing furniture, has a net operating income after taxes of $ 100
million, growing at 5% a year, and a cost of capital of 10%. Further, assume
that this firm has net capital expenditure needs (capital expenditures in
excess of depreciation) of $ 50 million, also growing at 5% a year, and that
there are 105 million shares outstanding. Finally, assume that this firm pays out
residual cash flows as dividends each year. The value of LongLast Corporation
can be estimated as follows:
Free Cash Flow to the Firm = EBIT (1- tax rate) - Net
Capital Expenditures
=
$ 100 million - $ 50 million = $
50 million
Value of the Firm = Free Cash Flow to Firm (1+g) / (WACC -
g)
=
$ 50 (1.05) / (.10 - .05) = $ 1050 million
Price per share = $ 1050 million / 105 million = $ 10.00
Based upon its cash flows, this firm could pay out $ 50
million in dividends.
Dividend per share = $ 50 million/105 million = $ 0.476
Total Value per Share = $ 10.00 + $ 0.48 = $10.476
To
examine how the dividend policy affects firm value, assume that LongLast
Corporation is told by an investment consultant that its stockholders would
gain if the firm paid out $ 100 million in dividends, instead of $ 50 million.
It now has to raise $ 50 million in new financing to cover its net capital
expenditure needs. Assume that LongLast Corporation can issue new stock with no
flotation cost and no
adverse signaling implications to raise these funds. If it does so, the
firm value will remain unchanged, since the value is determined not by the
dividend paid but by the cash flows generated on the projects. The stock price
will decrease, because there are more shares outstanding, but stockholders will
find this loss offset by the increase in dividends per share. In order to
estimate the price per share at which the new stock will be issued, note that
after the dividend payment, the old stockholders in the firm will own only $1000
million of the total firm value of $ 1050 million.
Value of the Firm = $ 1050 million
Dividends per share = $ 100 million/105 million shares = $
0.953
Value of the Firm for existing stockholders after dividend
payment = $ 1000 million
Price per share = $ 1000 million / 105 million = $ 9.523
Value accruing to stockholder = $ 9.523 + $ 0.953 = $ 10.476
Another
way of seeing this is to divide the stockholders into existing and new
stockholders. When dividends are increased by $ 50 million, and new stock is issued
for an equivalent amount, the existing stockholders now own only $1000 million
out of the firm value of $ 1050 million, but their loss in firm value is offset
by their gain in dividends. In fact, if the operating cash flows are unaffected
by dividend policy, we can show that the firm value will be unaffected by
dividend policy and that the average stockholder will be indifferent to
dividend policy since he or she receives the same total value (price +
dividends) under any dividend payment.
To
consider an alternate scenario, assume that LongLast Corporation pays out no
dividends and retains the residual $50 million as a cash balance. The value of
the firm to existing stockholders can then be computed as follows:
Value of Firm =
Present Value of After-tax Operating CF + Cash Balance
=
$ 50 (1.05) / (.10 - .05) + $ 50
million = $1100 million
Value per share = $ 1100 million / 105 million shares =
$10.48
Note that the total value per share is unchanged from the
previous two scenarios, as shown in Table 10.1, though all of the value comes
from price appreciation.
Table 10.1: Value
Per Share to Existing Stockholders from Different Dividend Policies
Value of Firm |
Dividends |
Value to Existing |
Price |
Dividends |
Total Value |
(Operating CF) |
|
Stockholders |
per share |
per share |
per share |
$1,050 |
$
- |
$1,100 |
$ 10.48 |
$
- |
$ 10.48 |
$1,050 |
$ 10.00 |
$1,090 |
$ 10.38 |
$ 0.10 |
$ 10.48 |
$1,050 |
$ 20.00 |
$1,080 |
$ 10.29 |
$ 0.19 |
$ 10.48 |
$1,050 |
$ 30.00 |
$1,070 |
$ 10.19 |
$ 0.29 |
$ 10.48 |
$1,050 |
$ 40.00 |
$1,060 |
$ 10.10 |
$ 0.38 |
$ 10.48 |
$1,050 |
$ 50.00 |
$1,050 |
$ 10.00 |
$ 0.48 |
$ 10.48 |
$1,050 |
$ 60.00 |
$1,040 |
$ 9.90 |
$ 0.57 |
$ 10.48 |
$1,050 |
$ 70.00 |
$1,030 |
$ 9.81 |
$ 0.67 |
$ 10.48 |
$1,050 |
$ 80.00 |
$1,020 |
$ 9.71 |
$ 0.76 |
$ 10.48 |
$1,050 |
$ 90.00 |
$1,010 |
$ 9.62 |
$ 0.86 |
$ 10.48 |
$1,050 |
$ 100.00 |
$1,000 |
$ 9.52 |
$ 0.95 |
$ 10.48 |
When LongLast Corporation pays less than $ 50 million in
dividends, the cash accrues in the firm and adds to its value. The increase in
the stock price again is offset by the loss of cash flows from dividends.
It
is important to note though that the irrelevance of dividend policy is grounded
on the following assumptions.
á
The issue of new stock is assumed to be costless and
can therefore cover the cash shortfall created by paying excess dividends.
á
It is assumed that firms that face a cash shortfall do
not respond by cutting back on projects and thereby affecting future operating
cash flows.
á
Stockholders are assumed to be indifferent between
receiving dividends and price appreciation.
á
Any cash remaining in the firm is invested in projects
that have zero net present value (such as financial investments) rather than
used to take on poor projects.
If
dividends are, in fact, irrelevant, firms are spending a great deal of time
pondering an issue about which their stockholders are indifferent. A number of
strong implications emerge from this proposition. Among them, the value of
equity in a firm should not change as its dividend policy changes. This does
not imply that the price per share will be unaffected, however, since larger dividends
should result in lower stock prices and more shares outstanding. In addition,
in the long term, there should be no correlation between dividend policy and
stock returns. Later in this chapter, we will examine some studies that have
attempted to examine whether dividend policy is in fact irrelevant in practice.
The
assumptions needed to arrive at the dividend irrelevance proposition may seem
so onerous that many reject it without testing it. That would be a mistake,
however, because the argument does contain a valuable message: Namely, a firm
that has invested in bad projects cannot hope to resurrect its image with
stockholders by offering them higher dividends. In fact, the correlation
between dividend policy and total stock returns is weak, as we will see later
in this chapter.