Main Contents Page • Part 1 • Part 3 • Part 4 • Part 5 • About the book
This document contains updates to my book, Global Financial Markets (Houghton Mifflin, 1994). It also contains information on developments and research in the international financial markets that might be of interest to students and professionals.
Contents
Chapter 6: Currency Prediction Versus Market Efficiency
Forward rate bias and expected inflation; New research
results
Chapter 7: Currency Forwards and the Futures Market
Futures in Speculation; Forwards in Speculation; A
problem's problem
Chapter 8: Foreign-Exchange Options
Quanto options--applications; Hedging options positions;
New research results
Main Contents Page Back to the top of
this section
Forward rate bias and expected inflation
See Chapter 5.
Main Contents Page Back to the top of
this section
Futures in Speculation
See Chapter 15, "Does Futures Speculation Stabilize Spot Prices? Evidence from
Metals Markets" by A. Enis Kocagil.
Forwards in Speculation
It is often difficult, especially in the context of a corporation's complex international
transactions, to separate hedging from speculative transactions in the foreign exchange
markets. In Example 7.4, Kodak is undertaking "selective hedging" of its current and
anticipated receivables. The action is speculative--it is precipitated by an individual's
forecast of the yen's direction, not purely by the company's natural business. In short,
the company, like most, is using its foreign-currency receivables as an excuse to take a
view on a currency in the hope of profiting.
This is, of course, a fictional example. The next one is real.
On February 20, 1993, Showa Shell Sekiyu, a Japanese oil refiner and distributor that
was 50% owned by Royal Dutch/Shell, reported that it had lost Y125 billion ($1.05
billion) in 1992. The firm's losses, equal to 82% of its shareholders' equity, stemmed
from $6.4 billion worth of speculative foreign exchange contracts. These were
accumulated by the firm's treasury department, apparently without authorization. The
contracts, taken out in 1989 and subsequently rolled over, bought the dollar forward at
an average exchange rate of Y145, to which level the yen had briefly weakened that
year. At the end of 1992, the yen was trading at Y125 per dollar.
In Showa Shell's case, because the losses were "unrealized," i.e. not closed out, they
did not have to be reported in company accounts. Banks in Japan routinely allowed
their counterparties to defer settlement of lossmaking contracts by rolling them over
until they were advised by the ministry of finance to desist.
A problem's problem
On page 200, in Problem 9., replace "in Figure 7.7" with "in Figure 7.13".
New research results
Fractals and Intrinsic Time - A Challenge to
Econometricians by ULRICH A. MULLER, MICHEL M. DACOROGNA,
RAKHAL D. DAVE, OLIVIER V. PICTET, RICHARD B. OLSEN and J.
ROBERT WARD.
Contact: Olsen, E-mail: info@olsen.ch, Olsen & Associates AG
Research Institute for Applied Economics, Seefeldstrasse
233, CH-8008 Zurich, Switzerland Tel 41 (1) 386 48 48 Fax 41
(1) 422 22 82.
A fractal approach is used to analyze financial time series,
applying different degrees of time resolution, and the
results are interrelated. Some fractal properties of foreign
exchange (FX) data are found. In particular, the mean size
of absolute values of price changes follows a "fractal"
scaling law (a power law) as a function of the analysis time
interval ranging from a few minutes up to a year. In an
autocorrelation study of intraday data, the absolute values
of price changes are seen to behave like the fractional
noise of Mandelbrot and Van Ness rather than those of a
GARCH process. Intraday FX data exhibit strong seasonal and
autoregressive heteroskedasticity. This can be modeled with
the help of new time scales, one of which is termed
intrinsic time. These time scales are successfully applied
to a forecasting model with a fractal structure for both the
FX and interbank interest rates, which present similar
market structures as the Foreign Exchange. The goal of this
paper is to demonstrate how the analysis of high-frequency
data and the finding of fractal properties lead to the
hypothesis of a heterogeneous market, where different
market participants analyze past events and news with
different time horizons. This hypothesis is further
supported by the success of trading models with different
dealing frequencies and risk profiles. Intrinsic time is
proposed for modeling the frame of reference of each
component of a heterogeneous market.
Main Contents Page Back to the top of
this section
Customized exchange-traded contracts
In mid-1994 the Philadelphia Stock Exchange, the self-styled "world's largest organized
market for currency options," announced that it would henceforth offer market
participants tailor-made trading and hedging tools, but with all the safeguards of a
regulated exchange.
In its first phase, the market offered customizable strike prices, a choice of matching
any existing currency pairs, and inverse (European-quoted) contracts.
This is an example of how futures and options exchanges are attempting to market
themselves more effectively as regulators cast a negative light on the over-the-counter
derivatives market.
Quanto options--applications
Quanto options, mentioned on page 234 in Chapter 8, sound exotic. They give the right
to buy or sell an unknown quantity of foreign currency, where the quantity depends
upon some market variable such as equity prices or interest rates. In fact, they have
some very down-to-earth applications. Three examples follow.
1. Quanto options can be useful to international equity portfolio managers who wish
to
take a view on share prices in a foreign market, but not on the exchange rate. Such a
portfolio manager might invest in a foreign market, purchasing shares valued at X units
of the foreign currency. One way to hedge this is by selling forward X units of the
currency. However if, after one quarter, the shares' value has changed by Y%, some of
the foreign investment will be exposed. To solve this, he can buy a quanto option
whose payoff depends on both the exchange rate and Y. Specifically, the appropriate
quanto to purchase will be one that will lock in the exchange rate at which not just X,
but X(1 + Y) units of foreign currency can be sold.
2. A quanto option could be useful to a corporation that plans to buy a fixed amount
of a
commodity in a foreign market at a certain date in the future. For example, a Japanese
utility may anticipate purchasing 20 million barrels of oil for the winter months. Instead
of hedging by buying a fixed dollar amount forward, the utility could employ a quanto
option where the number of dollars purchased at a fixed exchange rate depends on the
price of oil.
3. Quanto options are needed to hedge the risks entailed in writing a differential
swap.
Banks that write diff swaps guarantee to exchange the interest rate in one currency for
that in another, but the exchange is all done in one currency. For example, NatWest
may agree to pay (or receive), in dollars, the difference between US dollar and sterling
Libor every six months for two years. Hedging this requires NatWest to engage in
separate interest rate swaps in the dollar and sterling markets, and to use a quanto
option to hedge the dollar-sterling exchange rate risk. The quanto would assure
NatWest of the dollar-sterling rate at which sterling Libor could be exchanged,
whatever the level of sterling Libor.
Hedging options positions
Some readers have pointed out that the section on page 229 entitled "Hedging Options
with Futures Versus Hedging Options with Options" is a little hard to follow. (Even the
title is a mouthful.) I thought I'd amplify the ideas with an example and three diagrams.
Suppose we are FX options traders at a bank. In response to a customer's request, we
sell 100 at-the-money call options on sterling. (The market price of sterling is currently
$1.50.) We must now hedge the position.
From the slope of the options price line (see Fig. 8.8 on p. 226), the hedge ratio is 50%.
Hence to hedge the 100-option position with futures contracts, we buy 50 sterling
futures. We are now delta-hedged.
As the diagram below shows, hedging options with futures entails hedging with a
number of futures determined by the slope of, or tangent to, the options price line. But
this slope changes whenever the underlying currency's value changes. In our example,
when the price of sterling moves up, the options writer is underhedged (the slope has
increased), so we lose more on our short option position than we gain on our futures
position. When sterling falls, the options writer is overhedged, so we gain less on our
options position than we lose on the futures.
The reason for our problem is simple. We are using an instrument whose price line is
linear to hedge one whose price line is curved. The degree of curvature is measured by
the option's gamma, which is the second derivative of the price with respect to the price
of the underlying instrument.
The solution is to use options to hedge options: hedge a curve with a curve. The
proportion of one option we use to hedge another option is determined by the relation
between the deltas, the hedge ratios. The option we're selling has a delta of 50%. If the
one using to hedge our position has delta of 40%, then we would need more of it--100*50/40, i.e.
125.
As the next diagram shows, the hedging-gap is less even for a fairly big move in
sterling.
Even so, the hedging-gap cannot be zero unless the curvature or gamma of the options
we've bought, and those that we've sold, are identical. Being delta-neutral is not
enough. Normally the gamma of the one we've bought is greater than the ones we've
sold (we are "long gamma"), or vice-versa ("short gamma"). Gamma is a desirable
property for options one owns, and undesirable for options one has written. For options
one owns, the more the curvature the more losses are cushioned and gains
accelerated. As the diagram below shows, being short gamma (but delta neutral) gives
losses for large upside and downside moves. It's a little like selling a straddle.
New research results
"The Valuation of Black-Scholes Options Subject to Intertemporal Default Risk"
(OFOR Working Paper Number 93-03)
BY: DON R RICH
CONTACT: DON RICH
E-MAIL: drich@lynx.neu.edu
POSTAL: Finance Group - CBA, 413 Hayden Hall,
Northeastern University, Boston, MA 02115, USA
PHONE: (617) 373-3155
FAX: (617) 373-8798
REF: WPS94-289
The valuation of many types of financial contracts and contingent claim agreements
is complicated by the possibility that one party will default on their contractual
obligations. This paper develops a general model that prices Black-Scholes options
subject to intertemporal default risk.
The explicit closed-form solution is obtained by generalizing the reflection principle
to k-space to determine the appropriate transition density function. The European
analytical valuation formula has a straightforward economic interpretation and
preserves much of the intuitive appeal of the traditional Black-Scholes model. The
hedging properties of this model are compared and contrasted with the default-free
model. The model is extended to include partial recoveries. In one situation, the
option holder is assumed to recover alpha (a constant) percent of the value of the
writer's assets at the time of default. This version of the partial recovery option leads to
an analytical valuation formula for a first passage option - an option with a random
payoff at a random time.