After over two decade of high productivity growth in th 1950s and the 1960s, we observed a significant slowdown of productivity growth in the 1970s and 1980s following the first oil shock in 1973. The debate on the causes of this productivity slowdown has turned into a puzzle as the causes of the worlwide slowdown have not been clearly identified. The following two tables show the extent of this productivity slowdown.
Table 1. Total Factor Productivity Growth Rate
1950s 1.4% per year
1960s 1.4%
1970s 0.1%
1980s 0.5%
1990-95 1.7% (0.9% with chain-weight method)
Labor Productivity Growth Rate
1900-1970 2.3% per year
1950s 3.0%
1960s 2.6%
1970s 1.1%
1980s 1.3%
1990-95 2.2% (1.4% with chain-weight method)
Several explanations of the slowdown have been suggested but none has been found to be fully satisfactory (see Krugman "The Age of Diminished Expectations" Chapter 1 for a detailed discusssion):
1. Energy crisis in the 1970s (1973 and 1979 oil shocks).
2. Exhaustion of the post-W.W.II technological boom.
3. Low investment and savings rate.
4. High taxation of savings.
5. Excessive government regulations.
6. Low rate of public investment in infrastructures.
7. Decline of R&D investment.
8. Sociological explanations.
9. Decline in quality of education.
The 1990s puzzle.
The data for the 1990s have led to a new productivity puzzle. Until the end of 1995, when the fixed-weight system was being used to measure GDP and productivity, it appeared that there was a major resurgence of productivity in the 1990s: total factor productivity grew at a 1.7% per year rate while labor productivity grew at a 2.2% yearly rate. It appeared that a decade old (starting in the 1980s) process of corporate restructuring, reengineering, down-sizing had finally borne its fruits and led to a major resurgence of productivity in the 1990s.
However, the switch in 1995 to chain-weight metohd for measuring productivity changed drastically the picture: the new chain-weight data showed that in the 1990s total factor productivity grew at a dismal 0.9% per year rate while labor productivity grew at a 1.4% yearly rate, not much above the 1970s and 1980s rates. So the great resurgence of American productivity in the 1990s suddenly disappeared overnight by a statistical wand.
These numbers looked dismal because many economists believed that the process of corporate restructuring, reengineering, down-sizing of the last decade, together with the development and adoption of computers and information technologies in the corporate world, had led to a major resurgence of productivity. The new chain-wighted numbers seem to imply that such productivity resurgence never occurred.
In the debate that ensued in 1996, there were essentially two views.
On one side there were those, like Paul Krugman, who argued that the new measures of output and productivity were substantially correct and that the productivity benefits of the Information Revolution had been overstated. See his views in his February 1996 NY Times contribution to the debate.
On the other side, those like Stephen Roach (Chief Economist at Morgan Stanley) arguing that the new chain-weight method underestimated output and productivity because, among other reasons, of mismeasurement of the growth in productivity in the service sector. See his rebuttal to Krugman's view and contribution to the debate. On why computers might not have led to a major increase in productivity growth see also a recent NYT article.
The debate in 1996 on productivity was clearly related to the other debate on whether output and CPI inflation were mismeasured. The debate on productivity is also linked to the controversy on whether the economy is growing too fast and risks to generate inflationary pressures, the debate on the sustainability of the process of restructuring and down-sizing of corporate America and its effects on the income and wealth distribution..
The 1996 debate on productivity took a twist in May when Roach changed substantially his view on whether there was a structural increase in productivity growth in the 1990s. See his three revisionist pieces: MSEF May 8, MSEF May 9, MSEF May 14.
The switch in Roach's view was consistent with his strong views about the risks of a resurgence of inflation in the U.S. His argument on inflation risks was based on three points: 1) the productivity growth rates seen in the early 1990s were not sustainable because they were based on pursuit of "cost-cutting efficiency" rather than permanent "productivity growth"; 2) therefore one could expect soon a "worker backlash" that would drive up wage costs; 3) this wage backlash would therefore lead to higher inflation in 1996-97 as the economy was growing at a rate faster than its potential productivity.
The debate on whether the output and productivity of the service sector is correctly measured has also reached the Federal Reserve. In the Minutes of the September 24, 1996 meeting of the FOMC, several FOMC members expressed such an opinion that has been endorsed in public by the Fed Chairman Greenspan. Also, the fact that low unemployment and full capacity has not been associated with with higher inflation has been explained in part by the fact that productivity growth is likely to be underestimated. In words of the minutes:
This new Fed view of productivity and the low inflation risks in the economy has been challenged by Roach who has been the a strong proponent of the view that inflation is not dead and that we will probably observe a resurgence of inflation soon. Read his critique of the new Fed productivity play, his view of why productivity is on the wane and his skeptical view of the Slifman and Corrado study and Greenspan's "new paradygm".
For a different view, see the NYT
article on Dec 1, 1996 on how mismeasurement of CPI biases downwards
our productivity & real wage measures.
The 1997 Debate on the New Economy and the New Paradigm
In 1997, the debate on productivity growth took a new twist as data for 1996 and 1997 appeared to show a significant increase in the rate of productivity growth. For example the latest data for the third quarter of 1997 showed that productivity was growing at a annualized rate of 4.0% in the business sector and a whopping 9.3% in the manufacturing sector. While the annualized growth rate data might be distorted by a particular good quarter, the actual quarter-on-quarter annual rates of growth showed similar large increases of productivity growth: the actual productivity growth between the third quarter of 1996 and the third quarter of 1997 was 2.4% for the business sector and 4.6% for the manufacturing sector, well above the dismal rates of 1.0% observed in the early 1990s. These new data led a number of authors to argue that we had entered in a new era of sustained productivity growth; one heard a lot of talk about a "New Economy" where a "New Paradigm" of high growth and low inflation holds. The homepage on the New Economy on present an introduction to this recent debate.
For further data, information and discussion on the productivity debate, look into the Department of Labor home page on Quarterly Labor Productivity Statistics. The latest data on productivity growth are available there.